Skip to content

Revenue Risk Sharing for Highway Public-Private Partnership Concessions

December 2016
Table of Contents

« Previous

Appendices

Appendix 1 - Review of Existing Revenue Risk Sharing Mechanism

This appendix provides detail on revenue risk sharing mechanisms and related P3 programs in Chile, Brazil, and Korea to illustrate the context in which the mechanisms were derived. As shown in Table 6, the appendix also reviews mechanisms in Canada, Spain, and the U.K., and those for transit in various countries. Lastly, this appendix also discusses some mechanisms used in the U.S.

Table 6: Summary of Revenue Risk Sharing and Related Mechanisms By Country

Country Present Value of Revenues Minimum Revenue Guarantee Contingent Finance Support Availability Payment & Revenue Risk Revenue Distribution Mechanism Internal Rate of Return Balancing2 Innovative Finance Programs Shadow Toll Price Cap Rate of Return2
Chile              
Brazil                
South Korea                
U.K.          
Canada                  
Portugal                  
Spain            
Transit Cases1                  
U.S.            
1 In Canada, Columbia, Spain, Sweden, and the U.K.
2 In Section 3, these two mechanisms are discussed under the term "Regulated Return Mechanisms."

I.1 Chile: A Pioneer in Revenue Risk Sharing Mechanisms

Chile serves as a case study to understand the working of three risk sharing mechanisms: the least present value of the revenues (PVR), minimum revenue guarantees (MRGs), and Revenue Distribution Mechanisms (RDM). Its experience with more than twenty highway and infrastructure concessions spans over two decades. 3

I.1.1 Overview

Starting in 1992, Chile embarked on an ambitious P3 program for highways and other infrastructure. Many of the highway P3s were improvements of Highway 5, Chile's north-south road. They were implemented by the Chilean Ministry of Public Works (MOP). Table 7 shows the concessions awarded from 1992 to 2004.

Table 7: Characteristics of Chilean Highway Concessions (Vassallo, 2006)
Year of award Concession Highway Investment Total Investment Main Economic Tender Variable
1992 Túnel del Melón Interurban tunnel $38M $38M Mix*
1994 Camino de la Madera
A. Norte Concepción
Interurban
Interurban
$26M
$196M
$222M Mix*
Tariff
1995 Santiago S. Antonio
Nogales Puchancavı ́
Acceso a AMB
Talca Chillán
Interurban
Interurban
Suburban
Interurban
$180M
$12M
$10M
$169M
$371M Tariff
Tariff
Tariff
Tariff
1996 Los Vilos Santiago
Santiago Los Andes
La Serena Los Vilos
Interurban
Interurban
Interurban
$250M
$152M
$246M
$648M Tariff
Tariff
Tariff
1997 Chillán Collipulli
Temuco Río Bueno
Río Bueno Pto. Montt
Collipulli Temuco
Interurban
Interurban
Interurban
Interurban
$241M
$200M
$249M
$255M
$945M Duration
Upfront fee
Upfront fee
Upfront fee
1998 Santiago Talca
Santiago Valparaíso
Interurban
Interurban
$575M
$340M
$915M Upfront fee
LPVR**
1999 Costanera Norte Urban $384M $384M Upfront fee
2000 Norte-Sur
Red Vial Litoral Central
Urban
Interurban
$442M
$104M
$546M Upfront fee
Subsidy
2001 Vespucio Sur
Vespucio Norte
Talcahuano-Penco
Variante de Melipilla
Urban
Urban
Suburban
Suburban
$280M
$240M
$19M
$19M
$558M Upfront fee
Upfront fee
Subsidy
N/A
2002 Camino Internacional Ruta 60 Interurban $180M $180M N/A
2003 Acceso Nororiente a Santiago Suburban $165M $165M LPVR**
2004 El Salto-Kennedy Urban tunnel $70M $70M Upfront fee
* Mix: Several economic variables are employed. N/A: Information not available. **LPVR is the same as the term "PVR" used elsewhere in the Discussion Paper.

Chilean law required that concessions be financed with no more than 70% debt. The intent was to ensure that Developers had enough "skin in the game" so that they were focused on the project throughout the concession.

As was common in early P3 programs, Chile experienced poorly designed competitions and concession contract designs, volatile traffic demand, and political pressures to renegotiate failing projects (Vassallo, 2006). During the 1998-2002 recession, many concessions experienced difficulties with significantly lower than expected revenues. Many Developers sought to renegotiate with MOP. Engel et al estimate that 50 Chilean concessions were renegotiated in total 144 times, or more than three times per concession (Engel et al, 2014). These renegotiations put into question the credibility of the entire P3 competition process.

I.1.2 Least Present Value of Revenues and Variable Term Contract

Chile has been closely associated with development of the PVR mechanism in 1998, although the U.K. first pioneered a similar technique for projects in the Dartford Bridge and the Second Severn crossing projects (Engel et al, 2014, p.67). Under a PVR, the MOP sets the following parameters:

  • Construction program requirements;
  • Operations and maintenance (O&M) requirements;
  • Toll rate and schedule; and
  • Discount rate.

The Developer prepares the construction and O&M cost estimates, secures debt and equity commitments, and submits its bid for the lowest PVR that is acceptable to it. The winning bidder receives toll revenues during the concession. The revenues are discounted each year by the discount rate set by the MOP. The concession ends once the bid PVR amount is reached.

While Chilean law establishes a maximum concession period of 50 years, MOP can terminate PVR contracts after twelve years, allowing flexibility should project circumstances change, including the need for enhancements that the original Developer would not be able to or willing to take on, or if there were any other issues with the Developer (Engel et al, 2014). This is not dissimilar to a "put and call option" suggestion of Quiggin (2005), allowing an Agency or a Developer to terminate a concession contract through a pre-determined payment structure. Some U.S. P3 contracts also have such a mechanism in which an Agency must pay a portion, but not all, of outstanding senior debt if it terminates the P3.

The first highway PVR was Route 68 in Chile (Engel et al, 2014). The project was procured through a PVR process and received a minimum revenue guarantee (MRG), as discussed below. The winning bid came in lower than MOP's estimates, possibly because the MOP had underestimated how much the PVR and MRG mechanisms had reduced project risks.

The advantages of the PVR mechanism for Chilean P3s were as follows:

  • Revenue risk was reduced, thereby reducing the financing premium for such risk (Engel et al, 2000; Albalate, 2009).
  • It reduced the required amount of MRG that was required.
  • The early termination provision gave the MOP flexibility and leverage over the Developer in future negotiations, such as in pricing the cost of project expansions.
  • Payments to the Developer typically did not begin until project completion, incentivizing the Developer to meet deadlines, similar to "milestone" payments in APs.

A disadvantage of PVR was the perception that the Developer would earn a return regardless of the Developer's quality of customer service. They might not adequately manage O&M and/or devote too few resources to it. Demand is inelastic in response to service quality, as can be the case for highways, ports, water facilities, and airport runways (Engel et al, 2014). However, Engel et al argue that this is less an issue in road concessions, where service quality can be easily monitored through contracts with clear performance measures.

Academics have suggested a remedy to this is to have Developers specify key O&M costs, such as annual upkeep costs or major overlays, allowing for these services to be bid separately. This may make negotiating these costs between Developer and Agency easier, in those circumstances when project changes result in much different O&M costs, such as a tunnel or a road in an area subject to greater snow removal (Rus and Nombela, 2000).

PVR contracts were first used in Europe in Portugal's first highway concession, the Litoral Centro Highway. In that P3, the contract would end if one of the following events would occur:

  • If the present value of the revenues reached the bid mark (€784M) before the 22nd year of the concession, the concession would end in 2022. The year of award of the concession was 2003 (Vassallo, 2010).
  • If the present value of the revenues reached the bid mark between the 22nd and 30th year of the concession, the concession would end when the bid mark was reached.
  • If the present value of the revenues had not reached the bid mark by year 30, then the concession would end in that year, ostensibly at a reduced return or loss to banks and the equity investors, if they were not fully repaid.

The Litoral Centro Highway utilized the 12 month Euribor rate as the discount rate, providing a natural interest rate hedge. Later Portuguese P3 transactions, however, did not follow a flexible-term concession PVR (Engel et al, 2004, p.118).

I.1.3 Minimum Revenue Guarantees and Other Risk Mitigation Measures

Chile used the PVR mechanism in conjunction with other risk mitigation measures, including both direct and contingent subsidies (Engel et al, 2014). Of the 26 Chilean highway concessions between 1992 and 2004:

  • 15 were awarded with some form of upfront grant or subsidies;
  • 20 received MRGs; and
  • 22 included revenue sharing.

MOP offered MRG bands as high as 80%-85% of expected revenue with MOP paying the MRG if it fell below that year's guarantee level, for which bidders would pay a guarantee fee of 0.75% of the MRG amount. In one competition, two of four bidders did not want the MRG as the PVR adequately mitigated risk. Furthermore, Developers who opted for the MRG requested them to be weighted to the early concession years, reflecting Lenders liquidity concerns (Gómez-Lobo, A., 2000).

MRG payments were treated as another form of revenue in PVR bid projects and therefore included in the PVR amounts that the Developer received (Engel et al, 2000). This meant that MRG and PVR mechanisms could effectively be combined. PVR was both a bidding criterion as well as a method to equitably share revenue risk. MRG played an important role in providing short-term liquidity essential to cover debt service.

In non-PVR projects with a MRG, revenue sharing was triggered when the return of cumulative revenues reached an internal rate of return (IRR) of 15% (Gómez-Lobo, A. 2000). When that trigger was reached, the MOP would share with the Developer 50% of those revenues that exceeded the IRR trigger band (Vassallo, 2006). This cumulative IRR approach, a revenue "cap," is similar to many U.S. P3 provisions. In contrast, MOP paid the MRG on an annual basis when revenues were below the minimum, a revenue "floor," reflecting Lenders' needs. This is an "asymmetric" arrangement - cumulative for the cap and annual for the floor - but necessary to secure financing (Gómez-Lobo, A. 2000).

Table 8 shows that there were only four attempted Chilean PVR projects out of a total of 26 projects, two of which were successfully awarded (Vassallo, 2006). In the Talcahuano-Penco road (Ruta Interportuaria) concession, a PVR was offered, but bidders sought a subsidy instead.

Table 8: Use of LPV of Revenues on Toll Road Projects in Chile (Vassallo 2006)
Project Year of Tender Investment1 PVR2 Maximum Term Number of Bidders3 Situation
Santiago-Valparaiso 1998 $340M $381M 25 years 4 Successfully awarded, in operation
Costanera Norte 2000 $384M - 30 years 0 Not awarded, tendered again a year later under other economic variable
Talcahuano-Penco 2001 $19M - 31.5 years 2 Awarded, bidders requested a subsidy instead of PVR
Acceso Nororiente 2003 $165M $346M 40 years 1 Successfully awarded, in operation
1 Investment predicted by the government.
2 Present value of the revenues offered by the granted bidder.
3 Bidders in the last stage of the project.
I.1.4 Revenue Distribution Mechanisms

Due to the Chilean economic crisis of 1998 to 2002, many Developers sought to renegotiate concessions. To handle these renegotiations, MOP developed "Revenue Distribution Mechanisms (RDM)," which required Developers to make expansions to those projects in financial distress in return for one of three revenue guarantee alternatives, reflecting different annual revenue growth rates, of 4, 4.5, and 5 percent. Essentially, MOP required higher investments in return for guarantees of more revenues. These RDMs had a PVR element to them with the concession finishing early if certain revenue marks were achieved. It appears that most of these RDMs were carried out through bi-lateral negotiations, instead of open competitions, which raised the question whether MOP was receiving market-based bids. The renegotiations and the introduction of the PVR and RDM mechanisms are part of the evolution of the Chilean P3 program towards improved risk sharing arrangements, a theme common to many P3 programs.

I.1.5 Developer Exit Strategy

With the economy stabilizing and projects maturing, the ownership of the original Chilean P3s has changed. Chilean Developers have sold some or all of their concession interests to pension funds and other institutional investors once projects were completed and exhibited steady cash flows (Engel et al, 2014, p.88). This practice began in 2010 and as recently as July 2015, Hochtief sold a 50% share in the Tunnel San Cristóbal toll highway (Hochtief, 10/4/2012).

I.2 Brazil: Moving Towards More Revenue Risk Protection

Brazil evolved from providing internal rate of return balancing or regulated return mechanisms (RRM), contract extensions, relaxation of investment triggers, beneficial toll rate adjustments, to full MRGs. This evolution recognized the need to improve project financeability in light of overly optimistic T&R forecasts, yet it also increased the fiscal impact on Brazil's budget. 4

I.2.1 Overview

Brazilian P3s were authorized under two laws passed in 1995 and 2004: The "Toll Concession Law" (N.o8987/1995) and the "Public-Private Partnership Law" (N.o11.079/2004), respectively. Under the first, "Concessions" are projects that are fully funded by user fees, whereas under the second, "Public-Private Partnerships" are concessions that require a public subsidy (such as a capital grant or a service payment). Two entities under the Ministry of Transportation (MOT) manage P3s. The Brazilian Planning and Logistics Agency (EPL) manages national P3 policy, planning, and knowledge advancement and the Brazilian National Surface Transportation Agency (ANTT) directly manages concessions.

There are currently 28 highway contracts at the federal level, about 15 of which have been signed since 2000. A further 15 projects are to be tendered by 2016. Brazil experienced four distinct waves of P3 development, again demonstrating how P3 approaches evolve.

I.2.2 First Wave - 1980s to 2006

The first wave of Brazil P3s occurred in the 1980s and 1990s, during which the Brazilian government aggressively promoted P3s by offering heavily subsidized project debt from the National Bank for Economic and Social Development (BNDES). The debt tenor was generous, often matching the length of the concession of 25 to 30 years, similar to the TIFIA program's tenors of up to 35 years after substantial completion. Lenders typically required 30% equity contribution.

User demand during this first wave was very high, so actual revenues often exceeded forecasted revenues. In addition to strong demand, the more limited need for capital investment in these brownfield projects allowed Developers to earn healthy returns.

During this time, revenue risk was mostly assumed by the Developer. Concessions were awarded to the Developer offering the highest upfront fee, assuming a fixed tariff indexed to inflation that was determined by the Developer's business plan, which incorporated the Developers forecasts for traffic, revenue, operations costs, equity returns, and taxes. However, the Developer's demand risk was somewhat mitigated through adjustable tariffs. ANTT would track the project's actual rate of return against the Developer's forecast rate of return and ensure they "balanced" by adjusting the tariff appropriately. Known as the "balancing equation," this mechanism indirectly protected the Developer from revenue changes.

As a result of Brazil's high inflation during the 1980s and 1990s (Stratfor Global Intelligence, 2015), risk free returns were very high, driving up Developer IRRs to as high as 45%. Once macroeconomic conditions stabilized, equity IRRs settled to around 10%. ANTT introduced other mechanisms during this period to ensure performance, such as penalties and incentives for safety, construction delays, accident rates, etc.

I.2.3 Second Wave - 2006 to 2008

During the second wave of P3s, ANTT required higher levels of investment. Because it was imposing higher capital investment requirements on Developers, ANTT decided to assume more demand risk and alleviate the financing risk, making the following changes:

  • ANTT removed the upfront concession fee requirement and used the tariff level as a bidding criterion.
  • ANTT introduced a demand risk mechanism, the "investment trigger," allowing the deferral of 2nd stage capital investments (capex) based on traffic. For example, new lane construction would be triggered when demand met a pre-defined threshold. As illustrated in Figure 10, if the investment trigger was not achieved, the Developer would not make the 2nd stage capex and not take on more debt.
  • To prevent excess Developer profits, ANTT defined the IRR contractually in the concession, limiting it to 9% (Amorelli, 2009, p. 20).
  • In order to ensure fairness of rates for both users and the Developer, ANTT permitted toll rates to be revised every five years (Amorelli, 2009, p. 22).

Figure 10: Illustration of Brazilian Investment Trigger Mechanism

Figure 10

View larger version of Figure 10

I.2.4 Third Wave - 2009 to 2014

Following a period of failures experienced during the second wave which were exacerbated by the global financial crisis, ANTT introduced additional modifications to the "balancing equation:"

  • It included a schedule of tariff increases in the tendering criteria.
  • It relaxed the investment trigger requirement, permitting lower traffic levels of service before initiating the trigger.
  • It allowed Developers to extend the concession, although this has not yet occurred.
  • It also allowed direct payment for revenue shortfalls by ANTT throughout the entire operating period, called the "marginal cash flow mechanism."
I.2.5 Fourth Wave - 2014 to Present

By 2014, ANTT decided it needed to absorb more demand risk, as toll roads in this wave were not located in areas with as strong demand as those in the previous waves. ANTT introduced formal revenue sharing bands, with 50% of revenues in excess of ANTT's revenue forecasts shared with ANTT and shortfall of revenues below 40% of the forecasts paid as a subsidy. Through this mechanism, ANTT effectively provided a MRG, reducing the revenue risk.

Table 9 shows the evolution of the Brazilian federal P3 program's revenue and financing mitigation measures.

Table 9: Evolution of Brazil's P3 Program Related to Revenue Risk-Sharing
Risk Management Mechanism Focus of Mechanism Wave Function and Benefits
Balancing equation Revenue 1st Tariff adjusted so that actual revenues matched forecasted revenues. Provided downside protection but no MRG.
Investment trigger Financing 2nd Capital investment triggered by demand milestones. Not a revenue guarantee mechanism, but reduced financing risk.
Toll rate revisions Revenue 2nd Tariffs could be revised every five years. Not a revenue guarantee mechanism, but did reduce revenue risk. Same as IRR Balancing.
Relaxing of investment trigger Financing 3rd Further reduced financing risk by allowing demand to increase beyond original trigger's threshold.
Concession extension Revenue 3rd Extended revenue collection period. Has not been used to date.
Marginal cash flow mechanism Revenue 3rd Provided a subsidy in the event of a revenue shortfall.
Revenue bands Revenue 4th 50% of excess revenues are shared with ANTT, whereas the shortfall below 40% of the forecast are paid as a subsidy.

As can be seen in the table above, the early measures allowed the Developer to adjust tariffs or defer capital expenditures, addressing revenue and financing risks. The later measures provided subsidies in downside situations through a limited and then more comprehensive MRG.

I.3 South Korea: Evolving Minimum Revenues Guarantees

South Korea's experience best illustrates how a MRG mechanism evolved over time from being generous to one that appears to have a better balance of benefits between Agency and Developer. South Korea also used of innovative financing through government loan guarantees and upfront capital subsidies. 5

I.3.1 Overview

Spurred by rapid economic growth in the 1990s, South Korea initiated a number of P3s with the signing of the 1994 PPP Act and subsequent amendments in 1999-2000 that included a MRG (Park 2014). The South Korean government's institutions dedicated to promoting P3s included: 1) PIMAC (South Korea's key P3 agency), 2) the affiliated South Korean Development Institute (KDI), South Korea's leading think tank, and 3) South Korea's Credit Guarantee Fund, established to support P3s in 1994.

Under these acts, most projects were eligible for a 20-30% construction subsidy. The lowest required construction subsidy became the primary basis for award. Concession terms were fixed at 30 years but could be shortened or extended.

I.3.2 Minimum Revenue Guarantee Scheme 1999-2009

The initial MRG mechanism guaranteed 80% to 90% of revenues for the entire operations period. For example, the Soojungsan Tunnel had a 90% guarantee and 110% cap on forecasted revenues, while the Incheon Grand Bridge had an 80% guarantee and a 120% cap (Macquarie 2015).

Project debt was frequently guaranteed by South Korea's Credit Guarantee fund or provided by the government, so that the MRG served effectively as a "double guarantee" for debt, which helped in case the payments from South Korea's Credit Guarantee fund were delayed.

The Seoul Incheon International Airport was procured as a P3 at end of the Asian Financial Crisis in 1999 with the selected Developer bidding an IRR of over 20%. At the time the project was considered a national priority in preparation for the 2002 World Cup. PIMAC has had to pay a large amount of revenue guarantees.

Because of projects such as the airport, PIMAC realized it was over-exposing itself to revenue risk, so in 2003 it changed the scheme to cover just 15 years of operations with its exposure progressively reduced over time: 90% of the revenue was guaranteed for the first five years of operations, followed by 80% for the next five years, and 70% for the final five years, as shown in Table 10.

One of PIMAC's chief concerns with regard to the MRG mechanism was its continued exposure to most revenue risk while higher returns were all but assured to the Developer. Moreover, the scheme incentivized Developers to overestimate future demand, thereby allowing them to make more claims on revenue shortfalls. In fact, according to Kokkaew and Chiara (2011), PIMAC significantly exposed itself to this contingent liability because in most cases, actual revenues were falling well short of the guarantee levels.

In 2006, the revenue guarantee period was reduced from 15 years to 10 years, with 75% of the revenues guaranteed during the first five years and 65% guaranteed during the final five years. The MRG would also now apply only to solicited (but not unsolicited) proposals. The updated MRG scheme addressed PIMAC's concern regarding overly optimistic Developer forecasting by stipulating that the MRG was only valid if actual revenues were greater than 50 percent of the forecasted revenue ("50 percent feasible exercise condition"). The Seoul-Chuncheon Expressway, completed in 2009, followed this model (Macquarie 2015). This unique feature meant that Developers had to be highly confident of their forecasts, since there was no support below 50% of forecasted revenues.

The degree of revenue sharing by PIMAC varied by project, but only occurred when actual revenues exceeded the Developer's forecasted revenues. In the case of OOO Urban Railway PPP project, completed in 2002, PIMAC collected revenues exceeding 120% of forecasted revenue from operations years 0 to 5, and exceeding 130% from years 6 to 10 (Park, 2013).

I.3.3 Minimum Revenue Guarantee Scheme -- 2009 to Present

In 2009 PIMAC abandoned the MRG scheme and replaced it with a "New Risk Sharing Scheme." In addition, since September 2015, PIMAC has been developing a standard concession agreement, financial model, and RFP tailored to this new scheme, which works as follows:

  • The "Designated Risk Sharing Revenue" is no longer based on the Developer's forecasted revenue, but rather on an economically determined cash flow correlated to the project's investment cost and the risk free cost of capital. In essence, it is the gross operating revenue that guarantees an internal rate of return, only on initial capital costs, comparable to a five-year government bond, which can be updated every five years. This has some similarities to a rate of return approach as discussed below.
  • When the actual operating period revenue is less than the risk sharing revenue, PIMAC makes up the difference and pays the Developer the shortfall amount. The Developer is eligible for this scheme throughout the operations period.
  • In order to be eligible for the subsidy, actual revenues must still be 50 percent or more of the risk-sharing revenue.
  • When actual gross operating revenue exceeds the Developer's gross forecasted revenue, excess revenue is either used to lower toll rates or to fund future subsidies.

According to PIMAC, the new scheme has the following benefits:

  • It supports the private sector's investment throughout the operating period.
  • It reduces PIMAC's exposure by setting a maximum amount upfront rather an amount that could vary during the P3 term. It reduces Developer's moral hazard associated with the forecast "optimism bias" by anchoring the risk sharing revenue to the project's cost and the IRR at the government's risk-free rate of return.
  • It promotes interest only from Developers who can confidently bear significant downsides particularly during earlier years.
  • It reduces the overall cost to the public by transferring excess revenues back to the public to fund future subsidies or lower user tolls.

Table 10 shows how MRG levels progressively decreased from 80%-90% of forecasted Developer revenues for the entire concession period to 75%-65% in the first and second five years respectively, and to the latest scheme which was based on PIMAC's forecasts.

Table 10: Evolution of South Korea's MRG Levels, 1999 to 2009 (Park, 2014)
Period Years 0 to 5 Years 5 to 10 Years 10 to 15 Whole Period Additional Requirement
1999 to 2003       80% to 90% No minimum revenue requirement.
2003 to 2006 90% 80% 70% N/A Actual revenues must be at least 50% of forecasted revenues.
2006 to 2009 75% 65% N/A N/A Actual revenues must be at least 50% of forecasted revenues. Only solicited projects eligible.
2009 to present N.A. (New Risk Sharing Scheme introduced) Actual revenues must be at least 50% of forecasted revenues. The revenues are forecasted by the Agency based on investment costs and risk free interest rate.

Even with the 50 percent feasible exercise condition, past MRG schemes were subject to public criticism for excessive Developer profits and the disproportionate PIMAC revenue risk transfer, forcing PIMAC to substitute its own forecasts for the Developer's in the latest scheme. It is too early to know if this creates more VfM since new projects are not yet operational. However, competition under this scheme continues to be strong, so it does not appear to be a deterrence.

I.4 Evolution of P3 Programs in Chile, Brazil, and South Korea

The P3 programs in Chile, Brazil, and South Korea have evolved over the last two decades as these and other Agencies struggle to find the right revenue risk sharing balance. In order to understand why countries affected by the same revenue risk sharing issues take different approaches, it is important to acknowledge the differences in experience and issues each country encountered. In the case of Chile, frequent renegotiations led the government to conclude that Developers should be better protected from revenue risk. As a result, Developers were offered various mechanisms including PVR and MRG. Similarly, in Brazil the mechanisms offered to Developers provided increasingly more revenue risk protection.

In the case of South Korea, the rationale for changing their approach was different. South Korea started with a very lucrative revenue sharing mechanism, from the Developers' perspective, that resulted in returns perceived as excessive by the general public. In the face of public criticism, the Agency scaled back and reformed its generous MRG. Furthermore, it introduced a clause that would keep Developers from receiving public support if less than 50% of the projected revenues were realized. This unique clause exposed Developers to significant downside revenue risk, which is the opposite of what other countries struggling with revenue risk sharing have done. However, taking into consideration the previous experience with perceived excessive returns, the South Korean approach is understandable.

Programs in other countries have evolved as well, including in Colombia and Mexico. For instance, the short concession terms and low actual traffic in Mexico forced the government to bail out many road concessions.

Extrapolation from the experience of these countries to the U.S. must be done carefully. The general takeaways for the U.S., discussed in Section 3, are that:

  • Imperfect revenue risk transfer has resulted in renegotiations, which were either less transparent and/or threatened the competitive processes' credibility.
  • Contingent support mechanisms, such as MRGs, are promising mechanisms that U.S. Agencies may consider in improving financeability.

I.5 Combined Availability Payment and Revenue Risk Mechanisms

This section presents the experience in other countries that have utilized revenue risk sharing mechanisms in toll road and transit financings. Since there is less of a toll road tradition in these countries, these are more "one-off" examples rather than descriptions of evolving revenue risk approaches or programs.

I.5.1 A25 Bridge Availability Payment and Revenue Risk, Canada

The Autoroute 25 concession in Québec, Canada is a unique example of an AP P3 coupled with a revenue risk sharing mechanism. The project includes a four-lane 4.5 mile road and six lane 0.75 mile cable-stayed bridge between Montréal and Laval. Operations commenced in 2011. A dynamic toll system allows tariffs to increase beyond the maximum rate when the traffic reaches a certain threshold, serving as a congestion management mechanism (Parsons, 2015).

The 35-year concession includes four years for design and construction activities and 31 years for operation, maintenance, and rehabilitation activities. The Developer, "Concession A25," is responsible for design, construction, financing and operations. The Ministry of Transport has responsibility for toll collection and remittance of the toll revenues via APs. The APs are subject to availability and performance deductions (APEC 2014).

The revenue sharing mechanism works as follows:

  • Provided that the toll lanes are available and the electronic toll equipment is operational, the Agency will guarantee up to 60% of the Agency's forecasted revenues.
  • The Developer receives actual revenues between 60% and 120% of forecasted revenues.
  • The Agency and Developer share equally all actual revenues exceeding 120% of forecasted revenues.
  • An additional lane may be added in each direction should demand require it.

The AP component of this transaction is effectively a MRG. By including both downside protection for the Developer and upside revenue sharing, the Agency helped reduce the risk profile of the project while also potentially securing its own future revenues.

I.5.2 Variable Availability Payments in Spain

Some AP mechanisms in Spain allow the Developer to charge higher tolls depending on the Agency's road condition evaluation. This is similar to the remedy that Brazil allowed Developers in that country's IRR balancing mechanism. Such an approach only works if the demand is sufficiently inelastic, which has not been the case for Brazil and U.S. P3s. This approach contrasts with most U.S. AP mechanisms, which impose a penalty for poor road conditions (Vassallo, 2006).

I.5.3 Transit and Rail Examples

In transit concessions, Agencies can shift some of the revenue risk of bus, light rail and rail operations, and intermodal facilities to Developers. These are primarily arrangements in which the Developer is incentivized to increase ridership while still receiving a minimum payment for providing the service in the form of an AP. Some examples are listed below.

  • In the U.K., the $9B Channel Tunnel Rail Link concessionaire receives a partial AP. Approximately 60% of total revenues are based on availability and funded by the U.K. government. The remaining revenues are exposed to demand risk, from international rail companies. Besides this demand risk, the company is also subject to retail and parking revenue risk (Fitch Ratings, 2015).
  • In Vancouver, Canada, the $1.47B Canada Line, a light rail system, shifted some revenue risk to the Developer (10% of the AP). The other payment criteria were vehicle availability (70% of the AP) and quality of service (20% of the AP) (USDOT FTA, 2009).
  • In Stockholm, Sweden, private bus operators acquire their own vehicles, take fare revenue risk, and are responsible for collections and service quality. They do not control fares or service design, but can suggest routing and frequency efficiencies (APTA, 2015, p.10).
  • In Bogota, Colombia, the $1B TransMilenio bus rapid transit system shifted ridership risk to the trunk, feeder system, and fare collection operators. Each Developer receives a certain portion of total farebox revenue collected based on a pre-determined formula as well as availability and quality of service (USDOT FTA, 2009; Acosta, C., 2015).
  • In Madrid, Spain, Developers of five underground bus intermodal facilities are subject to some demand revenue risk based on the number of passengers per bus. This risk is partially mitigated since approximately 36% of revenues are derived from urban and regional bus operators who are required to use the facilities. A further 28% of revenues comes from interregional bus operators that are not required to use the facilities. The remaining 36% of revenues consist of commercial rent, parking, and other income. In a form of PVR, the concession term can be adjusted to ensure that the Developer's revenues are equal to the NPV of the original investment. The contract was subsequently modified to add an MRG which was set above the estimated number of users in the early years. This made it a deliberate subsidy, apparently as a way to compensate the Developer for construction requirements beyond those set in the concession agreement (Ciommo et al, 2009).

I.6 Shadow Tolls

Under the shadow toll approach, an Agency pays a Developer based on the traffic on a non-tolled highway or on a tolled highway whose revenues the Agency retains. The shadow toll concept was developed in the U.K. to incentivize Developers to complete construction projects more quickly and/or carry out capital improvements in a way that minimized traffic impact.

While shadow tolls eliminate tolling risk - the risk that users will find the cost or inconvenience of using the toll road too onerous - they do not mitigate traffic risk for the Developer. Furthermore, revenue risk remains with the Agency if the road is tolled. Shadow tolls complicate financing and create contingent fiscal liabilities. The U.K. has moved away from shadow tolls and instead uses the AP method extensively. U.S. Agencies have considered shadow tolls, but no major projects have employed this approach.

Florida DOT (FDOT) considered an innovative approach to shadow tolling in the case of a managed lanes project, the I-595 express lanes project in Broward County, Florida. In that project FDOT would have entered into an agreement with a Developer to manage both the managed lanes and general purpose lanes, incentivizing it to maximize traffic on both facilities, within the constraints of the managed lanes free flow requirements, "thus better aligning the concessionaire's compensation with FDOT's policy emphasis of maximizing throughput for the overall facility" (Florida Department of Transportation, 2009, p.11). This was intended to address poor managed lanes use when general lanes were full and toll rates or technological issues became a barrier to their optimal usage. Such an approach could provide greater public benefits (DeCorla-Souza and Barker, 2005, p.65), while still taking advantage of the Developer's superior management capabilities to operate the facilities. Such an approach might be achieved through a two part payment, consisting of an AP sufficient to cover debt service and O&M and a shadow toll payment based on peak period vehicle throughput. This payment structure could incentivize concessionaires to maximize use of managed lanes during periods of congestion (thereby reducing congestion on regular lanes).

In comparing shadow tolls with AP and design build finance (DBF) approaches, FDOT rated the shadow toll inferior to both approaches, with FDOT ultimately deciding to award the concession on the basis of an AP. FDOT's rationale was that Developers perceived the payment mechanism as riskier. Compared to the AP, FDOT's shadow tolls alternative assumed:

  • A lower debt to equity ratio, or leverage;
  • Higher interest rate or related costs;
  • Higher required Developer rate of return;
  • Lower tolls in earlier years, increasing in later years as demand increased.

The shadow toll mechanism FDOT considered was intended to align the Developer's financial incentives with the Agency's broader societal goals such as maximizing efficient use of the managed lanes facility. Such societal benefits could also be achieved under an AP, in which the payments to the Developer could, for example, be subject to 1) lane availability, 2) performance standards (including minimum speed on the managed lane), and 3) throughput on the managed lanes, provided that the Developer maintains full control over the dynamic tolling. Moving from a shadow toll to an AP transaction would potentially reduce the perceived risk while still allowing the Agency to pursue its broader economic goals.

I.7 Other Revenue Sharing Mechanisms

I.7.1 Rate of Return

The Rate of Return (ROR) model is used extensively to regulate electric utilities, which are natural monopolies. It allows firms to recover costs and earn a "fair" return by setting a regulated price, which is calculated by establishing the rate base and the value of all fixed assets used to produce the infrastructure at the agreed upon a rate of return. As discussed, South Korea provides its MRG on a similarly calculated rate base, but does not regulate the setting of toll rates.

Public utility commissions or their equivalent state regulatory agencies generally set prices on a periodic basis (such as every five years). The price base must guarantee financial feasibility, be lucrative enough to attract investment, and provide companies with returns similar to others with comparable risks (Buckberg, Kearney, and Stolleman, 2015).

ROR has rarely been used to regulate U.S. P3 toll roads. One private toll road, the Dulles Greenway, in the Washington, D.C. area, is regulated on the basis of ROR by the Virginia State Corporation Commission (VSCC), Virginia's public utility commission. The project entered technical bankruptcy in the 1990s, was restructured, and sold to Macquarie. Because of this loss of equity, VSCC has allowed Dulles Greenway to set its tolls as necessary, which Dulles Greenway has done subject to elasticity constraints.

I.7.2 Price Cap Regulation

Price Cap regulation gained popularity as a result of the deregulation of infrastructure in the U.K. in the 1980s and 1990s. Just as in the ROR model, the price cap mechanism protects consumers from excessive prices, while allowing the project sponsor to transfer the demand risk entirely to the private partner. The company is subject to price ceilings; yet the amount of revenues it receives are not regulated. The company maximizes its profits by fostering cost efficiency mechanisms. Price caps may also be set on a periodic basis, such as every five years.

As with ROR, U.K. price cap regulation has mostly been applied to large monopolies, such as utilities or commercial airports. It has generally not been applied to P3 toll roads.

I.7.3 United Kingdom's PF2 Public Equity

The United Kingdom (U.K.) is rethinking its approach to P3s under its new P3 program, PF2. This has included a new policy allowing the national government to serve as a minority investor in future P3 projects. The purpose of this approach is to:

  • Have greater alignment of interests between the public and private sectors;
  • Ensure that the public sector has greater access to project information and allow for increased transparency, including financial performance of the project company; and
  • Increase VfM, including more optimal sharing of project financial risk (HM Treasury 2012).

This approach is somewhat new for the U.K. and many other countries. However, some countries, such as Mexico, have required partial public ownership in infrastructure project companies, such as airports. Several questions will need to be answered in assessing this approach as a revenue risk transfer mechanism:

  • Does it increase the overall level of project equity and thereby reduce debt?
  • Will private shareholders receive a preferred dividend as has been the case in some similar arrangements?
  • Does this arrangement change the contractual obligations of shareholders to lenders?

This approach may be another way for Agencies to better share risk and is an area that needs to be researched once relevant cases and data become available.

Appendix II - Valuing Cost of Revenue Sharing Mechanisms

Determining the cost of a revenue risk sharing mechanism for an Agency can be challenging. In particular, mechanisms that include contingent liabilities, such as MRG and CFS, are difficult to evaluate quantitatively. However, in order to compare different mechanisms, an Agency may want to estimate the cost of different revenue risk sharing mechanisms. This Appendix provides a number of key considerations for evaluating revenue sharing mechanisms.

  • Traffic and revenue (T&R) projections: To evaluate any revenue risk sharing mechanism understanding the T&R projections is essential. Best practice suggests that Agencies should work with an investment grade T&R forecast from a reputable firm, sometimes prepared for the Developer, and a "Lender's" forecast prepared on behalf of the Lender. One or both of these forecasts should employ risk analyses to project T&R levels in severe downside cases, preferably in the form of a probabilistic T&R analysis (see Section 2.3 for more discussion). All of these forecasts should be reviewed and revised by Agency officials, T&R professionals, and others who are well-acquainted with the facility. The final base case and downside forecasts will form the basis of the analysis discussed below.
  • Fiscal impact: The nature of the revenue risk sharing mechanism and its underlying cash flows need to be fully understood. In particular, the Agency will need to evaluate how the Developer will be protected by each of the mechanisms under various (probabilistic) revenue scenarios as well as the fiscal implications on the Agency's balance sheet. This evaluation can be carried out using a separate financial model for each revenue risk mechanism to determine the cost to the Agency (and the protection to the Developer) under downside scenarios. The financial model developed for this Discussion Paper does this for each of the mechanisms. The model should consider both the costs to the Agency as well as potential toll revenues that the Agency may receive under the mechanisms. If the analysis uses a probabilistic T&R study, the Agency can develop a probabilistic projection of the fiscal impact of the mechanisms in any given year. The resulting cash flows give the Agency a clearer idea of the liabilities it is accepting.
  • Impact on financing conditions: Financing conditions depend to a large extent on the project's risk profile. If a mechanism reduces project risks from the Developer's perspective, financing conditions will most likely become more attractive. Specifically, Lenders may accept higher leverage, lower interest rates, and/or lower debt service coverage ratios. Equity investors may also lower their required return on equity. As a result, a revenue risk sharing mechanism that decreases the project risk profile will most likely result in a lower weighted average cost of capital (WACC) compared to a project with full revenue risk transfer. Bidders can therefore improve their bids (i.e. higher concession fee, lower required subsidy, more revenue sharing, and/or lower AP) knowing that they will be exposed to lower revenue risks, thus creating more value for the Agency. However, it is difficult to determine to what extent the WACC will be reduced under different mechanisms. As guidance, one could look at two extremes in revenue risk allocation. Under an AP, there is no revenue risk transfer to the Developer, which should be reflected in a lower WACC. Under a revenue risk concession, the full revenue risk is transferred to the Developer, leading to a higher WACC. A mechanism that shares the revenue risk between the Agency and the Developer would logically result in a WACC that lies between the two. However, the WACC is always project specific so generic numerical guidance is not possible. In order to evaluate the potential impact of a given revenue risk sharing mechanisms on P3 bids (and therefore ultimately on the Agency's budget/balance sheet), the Agency could develop a financial model and perform a sensitivity analysis on key P3 financing conditions (leverage, interest rates, debt service coverage ratios). This would help the Agency understand how a change in P3 financing conditions as a result of more or less revenue risk protection for the Developer may impact the Agency.
  • Combined fiscal impact on Agency: The ultimate fiscal impact of a revenue risk sharing mechanism depends on the payments it makes and the revenues it receives under the mechanism as well the change in bid values due to more attractive financing conditions. Ideally, Agencies would determine the net present value of both the fiscal impact of the revenue risk sharing mechanism cash flows on Agency as well as the change in bid costs due to different financing conditions, for all revenue risk sharing mechanisms. Due to the uncertainty of many of the assumptions, such quantitative assessment may be difficult. However, by undertaking the above steps, the Agency will be in a better position to evaluate qualitatively (and to a certain extent quantitatively) the potential fiscal impacts of alternative revenue risk sharing mechanisms.

Besides valuing the fiscal impacts of the alternative revenue risk sharing mechanisms, the Agency must also consider the mechanisms' impact on Agency accounting and budgeting. For example, the rules for accounting for contingent liabilities vary by state making it difficult to budget for liabilities beyond the current planning period, often no more than five years. The same is true for the credit rating agency recognition of toll revenues. As discussed, credit rating agencies will generally fully count APs on Agency balance sheets if they are reliant on toll revenues for at least the first three years of a new project.

Appendix III - Glossary

Term Definition/Explanation
Agencies DOTs and other public transportation agencies that provide highway and/or transit infrastructure and/or services.
AP Availability payment.
B Billion.
Concession Used interchangeably with P3, a long-term contract between a Developer and an Agency in which some or all of the following services are provided: design, construction, financing, operations, maintenance.
CFS Contingent finance support
Developers Usually organized as a special purpose vehicle, a company or a group of companies that provide some or all of the following services in a highway or infrastructure P3: design, construction, financing, operations, and maintenance. Developers are usually dominated by Strategic Investors, yet may include Financial Investors (see definitions).
DOT Department of transportation at a local, state, or federal level.
DSCR Debt service coverage ratio.
Equity Investors Strategic and Financial Investors. Most Developers include Equity Investors.
Financial Investors Private equity funds, pension funds, and other institutions that invest in infrastructure projects, independent of "strategic" motives, such as those of contractors, suppliers, or operators. See Strategic Investors.
IFI International Financial Institution (such as the World Bank, Inter-American Development Bank, European Investment Bank).
Lenders Financial institutions and their intermediaries that provide debt in the form of loans, bonds, and private placements. These can include commercial banks, credit agencies, investment banks, insurance companies, and government lenders (such as the USDOT TIFIA program or state infrastructure banks). Providers of deeply subordinated capital would be consider Equity Investors in this Discussion Paper.
M Million.
MRG Minimum revenue guarantee.
O&M Operations and maintenance.
PVR Present value of revenues.
P3 Public-private partnership, used interchangeably with concession.
Secondary Market The market of primarily Financial Investors that buy into concessions once the project has been completed and is operating successfully.
RRM Regulated return mechanism.
Strategic Investors Strategic investors are firms that make equity investments in a P3 with the goal of obtaining strategic benefits, such as a related construction, O&M, and/or supply contracts. Strategic Investors usually are the primary shareholders of most Developers. Once a project is completed and demonstrates stable cash flows, the strategic investor may sell some or all of its ownership in the P3 to Financial Investors, depending on the ownership requirements of the P3.
T&R Traffic and Revenue
TIFIA Transportation Infrastructure Finance and Innovation Act
VfM Value for Money
WACC Weighted Average Cost of Capital

Appendix IV - Respondent Organizations

From July 2015 to October 2015, in-person and conference call discussions were held with more than 25 representatives of the following types of institutions:

  • Agencies: primarily state departments of transportation and related state agencies;
  • Developers: U.S. and international firms active in the US;
  • Law Firms: Firms active in the U.S. P3 market;
  • Lenders: commercial banks, investment banks, and credit rating agencies; and
  • University, Think Tank, Policy Office: U.S. and international institutions whose academics, researchers, or policy analysts actively participate in this field.
Respondent Type Respondent Entity
Agency Brazilian National Surface Transportation Agency (ANTT)
Former P3 executive with the State Government of Minas Gerais, Brazil
Colorado High Performance Transportation Enterprise
Maryland Department of Transportation
North Carolina Department of Transportation
Texas Department of Transportation
Virginia Office of Public-Private Partnerships
Developer, Strategic Investor ACS Dragados
Cintra
Macquarie
Fluor
Former U.S. executive of US-based Developer
Kiewit
Plenary Group
Transurban
Financial Investor Meridiam
Law Firm Nossaman LLP
Lender Bank of Montreal
Barclays Capital
Fitch Ratings
Moody's
Standard and Poor's
Sumitomo Mitsui Banking Corporation
University, Think Tank, Policy Office Cornell Program in Infrastructure Policy
Polytechnic University of Madrid
Reason Foundation
South Korea's Public and Private Infrastructure Investment Management Center
University of Minnesota, Department of Civil, Environmental, and Geo- Engineering
U.S. Department of the Treasury

Appendix V - Literature Review

The academic literature is rich on major revenue risk sharing mechanisms as shown below. Engel et al have written extensively on PVR and on the challenges of P3 negotiations and economics worldwide. Vassallo has also written on Chile's PVR method as well as on other risk sharing guarantees and mechanisms used in P3s. A number of economists have written on estimating the costs of guarantees, such as Aldrete, R., A. Bujanda, G. Valdez-Ceniceros. The World Bank has published a number of case studies on country-specific P3 programs and guides on guarantees and P3 tools. The Discussion Paper relied on trade publications for data on more recent transactions and tweaks to MRG, CFS, and AP + Revenue mechanisms.

In Brazil, Chile, and South Korea, P3 programs and their respective revenue risk sharing mechanisms have evolved over the last two decades as Agencies struggle to find the right risk sharing balance, seek VfM, and ensure that Developers maintain interest in their P3s. Other countries, including Colombia, Mexico, and Spain, have undergone similar evolutions. Engel et al, 2014 has a comparative chapter and the USDOT FHWA, USDOT FTA, and trade groups like APTA have commissioned international case studies that provide analysis comparing country approaches.

The greatest literature challenge is to find analysis that gets "into the weeds" of specific transactions to evaluate how respective mechanisms actually worked - for Agencies, Developers, Lenders, and others. This analysis would require confidential forecasts and financial models from both Agencies and Developers. For some projects, a conclusive analysis of the value of the revenue risk sharing mechanisms cannot be made until the concession contracts are complete or at least nearly complete - in twenty plus years.

Acosta, C. (2015). Interview with Sasha Page in Bogota, Columbia, TransMilenio headquarters, November, 2015.

Adler, T. and R. Tillman (2015). Quantified Probability Assessment of Revenue Forecasts. 2nd. International Conference on Public-Private Partnerships. RT Consultancy / RSG.

Albalate, D. and G. Gel. (2009). Regulating Concessions of Toll Motorways: An Empirical Study on Fixed vs. Variable Term Contracts. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 43, 210-229.

Aldrete, R. and M. Bujanda (2012). Valuing Public Sector Revenue Risk Exposure in Transportation Public-Private Partnerships. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, No. 2297,2012, pp. 88-96.

Aldrete, R., A. Bujanda, G. Valdez-Ceniceros (2010). Valuing Public Sector Risk Exposure in Transportation Public-Private Partnerships. Texas Transportation Institute.

American Public Transportation Association (APTA) (2013). Millennial and Mobility: Understanding the Millennial Mindset. October, 2013. Retrieved 11/22/2015 from: https://www.ssti.us/wp/wp-content/uploads/2013/10/APTA-Millennials-and-Mobility.pdf.

American Public Transportation Association (APTA) (2015). Final Report: APTA Innovative Funding And Financing Study Mission, London, Stockholm And Munich. April 19-24, 2015.

Amorelli, L.C. (2009). Brazilian Federal Road Concessions: New challenges to the regulatory framework. George Washington University Institute of Brazilian Business & Management Issues, the Minerva Program.

Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) (2014). Infrastructure Public-Private Partnership Case Studies of APEC Member Economies. 21st Finance Ministers' Meeting, Beijing, China, October 21st to 22nd 2014. Retrieved 10/05/2015 from: http://mddb.apec.org/Documents/2014/MM/FMM/14_fmm_019.pdf.

Aziz, A. and K. Abdelhalim (2015). Comparative Analysis of P3 Availability Payments in the USA and Canada. 2nd International Conference on Public-Private Partnerships. Department of Construction Management / University of Washington.

Baeza, M., A. Ortega and J.M. Vasallo (2012). Risk Allocation in Toll Highway Concessions in Spain. Lessons from Economic Research. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, No. 2297, 2012, pp. 80-87.

Bain, B. (2009). Error and optimism bias in toll road traffic forecasts. Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. February 28, 2009. Retrieved 11/22/2015 from: http://www.pppcouncil.ca/pdf/S&P_tollroads_2009.pdf.

Brandao, L. and E. Saraiva (2008). The option value of government guarantees in infrastructure projects. Construction Management and Economics. p 1171-1180.

Buckberg, E., O. Kearney, N. Stolleman (2015). Expanding The Market for Infrastructure Public-Private Partnerships: Alternative Risk and Profit Sharing Approaches to Align Sponsor and Investor Interests. U.S. Department Of The Treasury, Office of Economic Policy, April 2015.

Carbonara, N., Constantino, N., Pellegrino, R. (2015). Revenue guarantees in PPPs: A win-win option-based model. 2nd International Conference on Public-Private Partnerships, Austin.

Cheah, C. and J. Liu (2006). Valuing governmental support in infrastructure projects as real options using Monte Carlo simulation. Construction Management and Economics, p: 545-554

Chiara, N. and M. Garvin (2007). Using Real Options for Revenue Risk Mitigation in Transportation Project Financing. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, No. 1993, 2007, p. 1-8.

Ciommo, F., J. M. Vassallo, and A. Oliver (2009). Private Funding of Intermodal Exchange Stations in Urban Areas: Case of Madrid, Spain. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, No. 2187, 20-26.

DeCorla-Souza, P. and W. Barker (2005). Innovative Public-Private Partnership Models for Road Pricing/BRT Initiatives. Transportation Research Record: Journal of Public Transportation, Vol. 8, No. 1, 2005, 57-78.

Diu, F. C. PPP renegotiations in Portugal: Motorway PPP case study. Public Private-Partnership Congress. Lima, June 4, 2014. Retrieved 5/11/2016 from: www.idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getdocument.aspx?docnum=38843098.

Engel, E., R. Fischer, and A. Galetovic (2000). Least-present-value-of-revenue auctions and highway franchising. Working Paper, University of Chile.

Engel, E., R. Fischer, and A. Galetovic (2002). A New Approach to Private Roads. Regulation, Fall 2002, 18-22.

Engel, E., R. Fischer, and A. Galetovic (2003). Privatizing Highways in Latin America: Is It Possible To Fix What Went Wrong? Economic Growth Center Yale University, Discussion Paper No. 866, July 2003.

Engel, E., R. Fischer, and A. Galetovic (2014). The Economics of Public-Private Partnerships: A Basic Guide. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Engel, E., R. Fischer, and A. Galetovic (2015). Soft Budgets and Renegotiations in Public-Private Partnerships: Theory and Evidence. Serie De Dcoumentos De Trabajo, Facultad Economia Y Negocios, Universidad De Chile, Departmento De Economia, SDT 408.

European PPP Expertise Centre (EPEC) (2011). State Guarantees in PPPs: A Guide to Better Evaluation, Design, Implementation and Management. (EPEC).

Feigenbaum, B. (2011). Risks and Rewards of Public-Private Partnerships for Highways. Reason Foundation, Policy Brief 98, December 2011.

Fitch Ratings (2015). Fitch Assigns High Speed Rail Finance (1) PLC's Tap Final "A-" Rating. April 22, 2015, 10:31 AM (EDT).

Florida Department of Transportation (2009). I-595 Value for Money Analysis. Prepared by Jeffrey Parker and Associates, Inc., June 2009. Retrieved 11/28/2015 from: http://www.transportation-finance.org/pdf/funding_financing/financing/i595_vfm_0609.pdf.

Flyvbjerg, B. in association with COWI (2004). The British Department for Transport Procedures for Dealing with Optimism Bias in Transport Planning: Guidance Document.

Flyvbjerg, B., M.K. Skamris Holm, S.L. Buhl (2005). How (In)accurate Are Demand Forecasts in Public Works Projects? The Case of Transportation. Journal of the American Planning Association, Vol. 71, No. 2, 131-146.

Gao, O., R. Geddes, and O. Rouhani (2015). Revenue Risk Sharing Options for Highway Facilities. Cornell University.

Garvin, M. and E. Gonzalez (2013). Fiscal Support Mechanisms For Public- Private Partnerships. Engineering Project Organization Conference (EPOC). Colorado: EPOC.

Gómez-Lobo, A. and S. Hinojosa (2000). Broad Roads in a Thin Country: Infrastructure Concessions in Chile. Washington, D.C. World Bank, Policy Research Working Papers.

Guasch, L. (2004). Granting and Renegotiating Infrastructure Concessions. Washington, D.C.: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

Hecht, J. (2015). Are Availability Payment Obligations Debt? Public Works Financing, September 2015, 16-17.

HM Treasury (2012). A new approach to public private partnerships. Retrieved 1/30/2016 from: https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/205112/pf2_infrastructure_new_approach_to_public_private_parnerships_051212.pdf.

HOCHTIEF, 10/4/2012. HOCHTIEF completes sale of Chilean toll highway. Retrieved 10/19/2015 from: http://www.hochtief-solutions.com/htsol_en/47.jhtml?pid=9211.

International Institute for Sustainable Development (IISD) and IMG Rebel (2015). Sharing Risk and Revenues from PPPs: Perspectives from current practice in the road sector. IISD.

Irwin, T. (2003). Public Money for Private Infrastructure. Deciding When to Offer Guarantees, Output- Based Subsidies, and Other Fiscal Support. Washington, D.C: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank.

Irwin, T. (2007). Government Guarantees. Allocating and Valuing Risk in Privately Financed Infrastructure Projects. Washington, D.C.: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank.

Park, T., Kim, B., and Kim, H. (2013). "Real Option Approach to Sharing Privatization Risk in Underground Infrastructures." Journal of Construction Engineering Management, 10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862.0000636, 685-693.

Kim, Kang-Soo (2013). Valuation of the Minimum Revenue Guarantee in the Urban Railway PPP Project. Korean Development Institute. Retrieved 11/28/2015 from: http://www.kdi.re.kr/kdi_eng/database/pop_summary.jsp?pub_no=13482&type=3.

Kokkaew, N., N. Chiara (2011). A Modeling Government Revenue Guarantees In Privately Built Transportation Projects: A Risk-Adjusted Approach. Transport, Vol. 28, No.2, March 2011, 186-192.

KPMG (2015). Public Private Partnerships. Emerging global trends and the implications for future infrastructure development in Australia. Retrieved on 05/15/2016 from: https://assets.kpmg/content/dam/kpmg/pdf/2015/06/public-private-partnerships-june-2015.pdf

Levinson, D. and K. Krizek (2015). The End of Traffic and the Future of Transport. Kindle Edition. EPUB.

Macquarie (2015). Minimum revenue guarantee summary. Retrieved 10/05/2015 from: https://www.macquarie.com/mgl/mkif/en/mkif-assets/minimum-revenue-guarantee-summary.

Moody's Investor Service (2012). Rating Action: Moody's assigns initial Ba3 rating to Aeropuertos Dominicanos Siglo XXI $550 million senior notes. October 29, 2012.

Park, S. (2014). Improving the Bankability of PPP with Proper Risk Sharing: The Korean Experience. PIMAC. June, 2014.

Parsons (2015) Autoroute 25 Infrastructure, Public-Private Partnership. Retrieved 10/08/2015 from: https://www.parsons.com/project/a25-ppp/.

PricewaterhouseCoopers (PWC) (2011). Funding Infrastructure: Time for a new approach? Retrieved 05/15/2016 from: https://www.pwc.com/gx/en/psrc/pdf/time-for-a-new-approach.pdf.

Quiggin, J. (2005). Public-Private Partnerships: Options for Improved Risk Allocation. Policy Forum: Financing Public Infrastructure. The Australian Economic Review, vol. 38, no. 4, pp. 445-50.

Rus, G.D. and G. Nombela (2000). Least Present Value of Net Revenue: a new auction-mechanism for highway concessions. MPRA Paper No. 12203, posted December 18, 2008.

Rus, G.D. and G. Nombela (2003). Flexible-Term Contracts for Road Franchising. Working Paper, University of Las Palmas (Spain).

Sanchez-Solino, A. and J. M. Vasallo (2006). Minimum Income Guarantee in Transportation Infrastructure Concessions in Chile. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, No. 1960, 15-22.

Sanchez-Solino, A. and J. M. Vasallo (2007). Subordinated Public Participation Loans for Financing Toll Highway Concessions in Spain. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, No. 1996, 22-28.

Shan, L., M. Garvin, and R. Kumar (2010). Collar options to manage revenue risks in real toll public-private partnership transportation projects. Construction Management and Economics, 28: 10, 1057 - 1069.

Stratfor Global Intelligence (2015). Brazilian Growth and Inflation. Retrieved on 10/07/2015 from: https://worldview.stratfor.com/article/brazilian-growth-and-inflation.

Tollroads, 2014. $1.4 Billion Refinancing Improves Long-Term Debt Structure for the 73 Toll Road. Retrieved on 11/22/2015 from: https://thetollroads.com/news/newsroom/newsroom/pressreleases/archive/201410/pr-20141022-14-billion-refinancing-improves-long-t.php.

U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration, Office of Highway Policy Information (USDOT FHWA OHPI) (2015). Traffic Volume Trends. Retrieved 10/16/2015 from: https://www.fhwa.dot.gov/policyinformation/travel_monitoring/tvt.cfm.

U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration, TIFIA Program (USDOT TIFIA) (2015). Projects Financed by TIFIA. Retrieved 10/24/15 from: https://www.transportation.gov/tifia/projects-financed.

U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Transit Administration (USDOT FTA) (2009). Foreign Public Private Partnership (PPP) Case Study Analysis Report: Canada Line, London Underground, TransMilenio, and Southern Cross Station.

United States Department of Transportation (2009). Public Policy Considerations in Public-Private Partnership (PPP) Arrangements.

Valsangkar, P. (2008). Revenue Sharing Models in a Public Private Partnership (PPP) Context. Computer Society of India.

Vassallo, J. M. (2006). Traffic Risk Mitigation in Highway Concession Projects: The Experience of Chile. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, Volume 4, Part 3, September 20-06, 359-281.

Vassallo, J. M. (2010). Flexible-Term Highway Concessions How Can They Work Better? Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, No. 2187, 1-8.

Vecchi, V., E. Amadio, E. Borgonovo, N. Cusumano, S. Gatti, (2015). Can public manager competencies offset the bidding opportunism generated by public guarantees issued to increase the bankability of PPP projects? Evidences from a multi agent simulation. Bocconi University.

World Bank Group (2015). GDP per capita (current US$). Retrieved 11/22/2015 from: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.CD.

World Bank Group and Gobierno de España (2012). Best Practices in Public-Private Partnerships Financing in Latin America: The Role of Guarantees. Washington, D.C.: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

 

Footnotes

3 This case primarily relies on published evaluations, in particular of Engel et al (2000, 2002, 2003, 2014) and Vassallo (2006).

4 This case was developed with published materials, an interview with representatives of ANTT on August 17, 2015 organized by the FHWA, and with Marcos Siqueira Moraes, Former Head of the PPP Unit of the State Government of Minas Gerais, and founding partner of the consulting company Radar PPP on 09/15/2015.

5 This case study drew upon both published materials and an interview with Soojin Park, the head of the Policy Team for South Korea's Public and Private Infrastructure Investment Management Center (PIMAC).

« Previous

back to top